Immigration’s Economic Impact
June 20, 2007
PDF (53K)
"Our review of economic research finds immigrants not only help fuel the Nation's economic
growth, but also have an overall positive effect on the income of native-born workers."
-Council of Economic Advisers Chairman Edward P. Lazear
Introduction
In 2006, foreign-born workers accounted for 15% of the U.S. labor force, and over the last
decade they have accounted for about half of the growth in the labor force. That immigration has
fueled U.S. macroeconomic growth is both uncontroversial and unsurprising – more total
workers yield more total output. That immigrant workers benefit from working in the United
States is also uncontroversial and unsurprising – few would come here otherwise.1
Assessing how immigration affects the well-being of U.S. natives is more complicated. This is
because immigration’s economic impact is complex and may play out over generations, and
because not all natives are alike in terms of their economic characteristics. Even in retrospect it
is not easy to distinguish the influence of immigration from that of other economic forces at
work at the same time. Nor is it easy to project costs and benefits far into the future.
Nonetheless, economists and demographers have made headway on many of the measurement
problems. This white paper assesses immigration’s economic impact based on the professional
literature and concludes that immigration has a positive effect on the American economy as a
whole and on the income of native-born American workers.
Key Findings
- On average, US natives benefit from immigration. Immigrants tend to complement (not
substitute for) natives, raising natives’ productivity and income.
- Careful studies of the long-run fiscal effects of immigration conclude that it is likely to
have a modest, positive influence.
- Skilled immigrants are likely to be especially beneficial to natives. In addition to
contributions to innovation, they have a significant positive fiscal impact.
General Points
- Immigrants are a critical part of the U.S. workforce and contribute to productivity
growth and technological advancement. They make up 15% of all workers and even larger
shares of certain occupations such as construction, food services and health care.
Approximately 40% of Ph.D. scientists working in the United States were born abroad.
(Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics; American Community Survey)
- Many immigrants are entrepreneurs. The Kauffman Foundation’s index of
entrepreneurial activity is nearly 40% higher for immigrants than for natives. (Source:
Kauffman Foundation)
- Immigrants and their children assimilate into U.S. culture. For example, although 72%
of first-generation Latino immigrants use Spanish as their predominant language, only 7% of
the second generation are Spanish-dominant. (Source: Pew Hispanic Center/Kaiser Family
Foundation)
- Immigrants have lower crime rates than natives. Among men aged 18 to 40, immigrants
are much less likely to be incarcerated than natives. (Source: Butcher and Piehl)
- Immigrants slightly improve the solvency of pay-as-you-go entitlement programs such
as Social Security and Medicare. The 2007 OASDI Trustees Report indicates that an
additional 100,000 net immigrants per year would increase the long-range actuarial balance
by about 0.07% of taxable payroll. (Source: Social Security Administration)
- The long-run impact of immigration on public budgets is likely to be positive.
Projections of future taxes and government spending are subject to uncertainty, but a careful
study published by the National Research Council estimated that immigrants and their
descendants would contribute about $80,000 more in taxes (in 1996 dollars) than they would
receive in public services. (Source: Smith and Edmonston)
1. Evaluating the Effect of Immigration on the Income of Natives
Immigrants not only change the size of the labor force, they change the relative supplies of
factors such as unskilled labor, skilled labor, and capital in the economy. US natives tend to
benefit from immigration precisely because immigrants are not exactly like natives in terms of
their productive characteristics and factor endowments. For example, Chart 1 shows that in
contrast to their 15% share in the total labor force, foreign-born workers accounted for much
higher proportions of workers without high school degrees and of those with Ph.D. degrees
(especially for those working in scientific occupations). Differences between natives and
immigrants lead to production complementarities that benefit natives.
Example:
- The presence of unskilled foreign-born construction laborers allows skilled US
craftsmen and contractors to build more homes at lower cost than otherwise –
therefore the US natives’ productivity and income rise.
- Thus, when immigrants are added to the US labor force, they increase the economy’s
total output, which is split between immigrants (who receive wages) and natives (who
receive wages and also earn income from their ownership of physical and human
capital). Natives may also gain from having a wider variety of goods and services to
consume and from lower prices for the goods and services produced by industries
with high concentrations of foreign-born workers.
The "immigration surplus" is a simple and frequently cited metric of natives’ total gains from
immigration. The surplus accrues to native factors of production that are complemented by
immigrant workers – that is, to factors whose productivity is enhanced by the presence of
immigrants. In a simple model with just capital and labor (not differentiated by skill), similar in
structure to that presented in the National Research Council (NRC) analysis, one can estimate
this surplus as the area of a triangle defined by a downward sloping labor demand curve and the
shift in labor supply attributed to immigration. Using a standard estimate of labor demand
elasticity (0.3) and measures of the foreign-born share of the labor force, the current immigration
surplus is about 0.28% of GDP, or roughly $37 billion per year.2
Although the simplicity of the "immigration surplus" approach is attractive, the implicit
assumptions are numerous, and it is well-understood by economists that this is not a full
reckoning of immigration’s influence on the economy. For example, the approach does not
differentiate between different kinds of workers (by skill, experience or nativity) and does not
allow for an endogenous and positive capital market response to the change in labor supply.
Because immigration changes the mix of factors in the economy, it may influence the pattern of
factor prices, which in turn may induce endogenous changes in other factor supplies. Moreover, implicit in the surplus calculation is an assumed negative effect on average wages for natives –
an effect that is difficult to detect in empirical studies of the U.S. wage structure.3
A more complex approach to measuring the influence of immigration on natives’ income
differentiates workers by skill, nativity, and experience and also allows for a capital
accumulation response to changes in the supply of labor. In this scenario complementarities
from immigrant workers are allowed to accrue to native workers. A recent paper by Ottaviano
and Peri (2006) takes such an approach to measuring the wage effects of immigration and
concludes that immigration since 1990 has boosted the average wage of natives by between 0.7%
and 1.8% depending on the assessment’s timeframe – the effect is more positive when the capital
stock has had time to adjust.4 Fully 90% of US native-born workers are estimated to have gained
from immigration. Multiplying the average percentage gains by the total wages of US natives
suggests that annual wage gains from immigration are between $30 billion and $80 billion.5
In both approaches described above, natives benefit from immigration because the
complementarities associated with immigrants outweigh any losses from added labor market
competition. Rather than focusing on average effects, special attention could be paid to the wellbeing
of the least-skilled natives. The number of natives with less than a high school degree has
declined over time, which is one reason less-skilled immigrants have been drawn into the US
labor force to fill relatively low-paying jobs. Even so, based on Chart 1, one might expect the
remaining least-skilled natives to face labor market competition from immigrants.6 Evidence on
this issue is mixed. Studies often find small negative effects of immigration on the wages of
low-skilled natives, and even the comparatively large estimate reported in Borjas (2003) is under
10% for immigration over a 20 year period.7 The difficulties faced by high school dropouts are a
serious policy concern, but it is safe to conclude that immigration is not a central cause of those
difficulties, nor is reducing immigration a well-targeted way to help these low-wage natives.
- Conclusion: Immigrants increase the economy’s total output, and natives share in part of
that increase because of complementarities in production. Different approaches to
estimating natives’ total income gains from immigration yield figures over $30 billion per
year. Sharply reducing immigration would be a poorly-targeted and inefficient way to
assist low-wage Americans.
2. Evaluating the Fiscal Benefits and Costs
To assess the fiscal implications of immigration, it is important to take a long-term view of the
process and its interaction with projected demographic and economic trends. The National
Research Council (NRC) published a landmark study of immigration in 1997, including an
assessment of the overall fiscal impact (incorporating taxes and benefits at all levels of
government).8 Although 10 years have passed since its publication, the volume’s basic
methodological lessons and empirical results are worth repeating.9
One key point is that "snapshot" views of immigration’s fiscal impact, particularly when based
on analysis of households headed by immigrants, are insufficient and potentially misleading
guides to immigration’s long-run fiscal impact.10 Instead, "Only a forward-looking projection of
taxes and government spending can offer an accurate picture of the long-run fiscal consequences
of admitting new immigrants" (Smith and Edmonston 1997, p. 10). This approach captures the
full costs and benefits of the children of immigrants. Of course, such projections must rely on
assumptions about the future path of taxes and government spending as well as economic and
demographic trends. From this long-run point of view, the NRC study estimated that immigrants
(including their descendants) would have a positive fiscal impact – a present discounted value of
$80,000 per immigrant on average in their baseline model (in 1996 dollars).11 The surplus is
larger for high-skilled immigrants ($198,000) and slightly negative for those with less than a
high school degree (-$13,000). It is worth noting that the NRC’s estimated fiscal cost from lessskilled
workers is far smaller than some commentators have recently suggested based on less
satisfactory methods.
The long-term fiscal approach imparts four main lessons: 1) although subject to uncertainty, it
appears that immigration has a slightly positive long-run fiscal impact; 2) skilled immigrants
have a more positive impact than others; 3) the positive fiscal impact tends to accrue at the
federal level, but net costs tend to be concentrated at the state and local level; and 4) the overall
fiscal effect of immigration is not large relative to the volume of total tax revenues – immigration
is unlikely to cure or cause significant fiscal imbalances.
- Conclusion: Although subject to the uncertainties inherent to long-run projections,
careful forward-looking estimates of immigration’s fiscal effects, accounting for all
levels of government spending and tax revenue, suggest a modest positive influence on
average. The fiscal impact of skilled immigrants is more strongly positive.
3. Immigrants in the U.S. Labor Force
From the perspective of workers in many countries today, the potential income gains from
migration are large. For example, Hanson (2006) measured average wages for Mexican-born
men who had recently moved to the United States and compared them to the wages of similar
men who were still working in Mexico.12 The real wage ratios (that is, wages adjusted for
international differences in prices) ranged from about 6-to-1 to 2-to-1 in favor of the U.S.-based
workers, depending on the age and education group. Facing such large international wage
differences, a worker might hope to move to the U.S. permanently or with the expectation of
returning home after accumulating some savings. In this scenario the opportunity to work
abroad temporarily can help finance large purchases or investments (like a house, car, or new
business) in home countries where credit markets are underdeveloped and where wealth
accumulation is difficult due to low wages. Migration might also allow households to expand
and diversify their income sources, thereby serving as a lifeline to a higher and more stable
income level for family members who remain based in a less-developed economy. In short, the
economic gains to immigrants and their families are typically quite large.
These immigrants, like those in the past, work hard to improve their lot and that of their children.
Their labor force participation rate, reflecting their concentration in prime working ages, is
somewhat higher than that of natives (69% versus 66% in 2006), and conditional on being in the
labor force their unemployment rate is somewhat lower than that of natives (4.0% versus 4.7% in
2006).13 Although their average income level is lower than natives’, Table 1 shows that they do
fairly well in comparison with natives who have similar levels of education. Immigrants have
low rates of incarceration compared to natives.14 And they are more likely to engage in
entrepreneurial activity.15 Children of Latino immigrants overwhelmingly learn English.16
Finally, relative to natives, the children of low-education immigrants narrow much of the
educational and income gap that their parents faced.17
- Conclusion: As in the past, immigrants evince a strong work ethic, and the children of
immigrants tend to assimilate in terms of language acquisition and educational
attainment.
1 This document will use "immigrant" and "foreign born" interchangeably. The terms encompass both legal and
illegal migrants. Because it is difficult to determine the legal status of migrants in standard data sets, the economics
literature generally assesses all foreign-born workers together.
2 Arithmetically, as a share of GDP the surplus is approximated by one-half times labor’s share of income times the
proportional increase in employment times the estimated wage adjustment to a supply shift of that size. Varying the
assumed elasticity of labor demand changes the estimated surplus proportionally. An elasticity of 0.1 yields a
surplus estimate of $12 billion, whereas an elasticity of 0.5 yields surplus estimate of $62 billion. The approach is
discussed at some length in chapter 4 of J. Smith and B. Edmonston (eds.), The New Americans: Economic,
Demographic, and Fiscal Effects of Immigration, Washington DC: National Research Council, National Academy
Press, 1997. The NRC’s rough immigration surplus estimate was $14 billion in 1996. The larger 2006 figure here is
due to a larger economy, inflation to 2006 dollars, and growth in the immigrant share of the workforce.
3 See, for instance, D. Card, "Is the New Immigration Really So Bad?" NBER Working Paper 11547 (2005) or R.
Friedberg and J. Hunt, "The Impact of Immigration on Host Country Wages, Employment and Growth," Journal of
Economic Perspectives 9 (1995): 23-44.
4 The 1.8% figure is based on Ottaviano and Peri’s "median" value for the elasticity of substitution between native
and foreign-born workers within education-experience groups (6.6). Varying the parameter from 5 to 10 yields
long-run average wage gains ranging from 2.3% to 1.2%. See G. Ottaviano and G. Peri, "Rethinking the Effects of
Immigration on Wages," NBER Working Paper 12497 (2006).
5 Total wages earned by US natives were calculated using the 2005 American Community Survey.
6 Note that even within categories defined by education and experience levels, natives may have language skills and
local knowledge that substantially differentiate them from immigrants.
7 G. Borjas, "The Labor Demand Curve Is Downward Sloping: Reexamining the Impact of Immigration on the
Labor Market," Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (2003): 1335-1374. The figure cited in the text appears on p.
1369. G. Ottaviano and G. Peri (2006), using an approach that builds directly on Borjas (2003), estimate a negative
effect of only 1% to 2% for the least-skilled natives. A key methodological difference is that Ottaviano and Peri
allow for imperfect substitution between immigrants and natives within education-experience cells. Card (2005)
also questions whether immigrants substantially lower the wages of unskilled natives.
8 J. Smith and B. Edmonston (eds.), The New Americans: Economic, Demographic, and Fiscal Effects of
Immigration, Washington DC: National Research Council, National Academy Press, 1997.
9 For a more recent but parallel investigation, see R. Lee and T. Miller, "Immigration, Social Security, and Broader
Fiscal Impacts," American Economic Review 90, 2 (May 2000): 350-354.
10 For example, see R. Rector and C. Kim, "The Fiscal Cost of Low-Skill Immigrants to the U.S. Taxpayer,"
Washington, DC: Heritage Foundation, 2007.
11 The NRC volume estimated that the limitations on public benefits in the 1996 Personal Responsibility and Work
Opportunity Reconciliation Act would raise the fiscal impact by an additional $8,000 on average. The NRC
baseline model assumed that the debt-GDP ratio would be stabilized after 20 years by a 50-50 combination of falling
government spending and rising taxes. The report discusses alternative scenarios and concludes that the basic
results are not strongly affected by the assumed mix of adjustment of benefits versus taxes (Smith and Edmonston
1997, p. 338).
12 G. Hanson, "Illegal Migration from Mexico to the United States," Journal of Economic Literature, 44 (2006):
869-924.
13 http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/forbrn.pdf.
14 See Anne Morrison Piehl’s testimony before the U.S. House of Representatives Committee on the Judiciary,
Subcommittee on Immigration, Citizenship, Refugees, Border Security, and International Law (May 17, 2007),
available at http://judiciary.house.gov/media/pdfs/Piehl070517.pdf. Piehl, an economist at Rutgers University,
testified that "…there is no empirical evidence that immigrants pose a particular crime threat. In contrast, the
evidence points to immigrants having lower involvement in crime than natives. The direct evidence on crime rates
shows that localities that receive large numbers of immigrants do not experience increases in relative crime rates."
15 See the Kauffman Foundation’s index of entrepreneurial activity (available at www.kauffman.org).
16 See the Pew Hispanic Center/Kaiser Family Foundation 2002 National Survey of Latinos, summary results are
available at: http://pewhispanic.org/files/execsum/15.pdf.
17 See D. Card, "Is the New Immigration Really So Bad?" NBER Working Paper 11547 (2005). Also See D. Card,
J. DiNardo, and E. Estes, "The More Things Change: Immigrants and the Children of Immigrants in the 1940s,
1970s, and the 1990s," in G. Borjas (ed.), Issues in the Economics of Immigration. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 2000.
Additional Reading
G. Borjas, Heaven’s Door: Immigration Policy and the American Economy, Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1999.
D. Card, "Is the New Immigration Really So Bad?" NBER Working Paper 11547 (2005).
http://www.nber.org/papers/w11547.
D. Card, J. DiNardo, and E. Estes, "The More Things Change: Immigrants and the Children of
Immigrants in the 1940s, 1970s, and 1990s," NBER Working Paper 6519 (1998).
http://www.nber.org/papers/w6519.
Council of Economic Advisers, Economic Report of the President, Washington DC: United
States Government Printing Office, 2007. Chapter 9, "Immigration."
/cea/ch9-erp07.pdf.
Council of Economic Advisers, Economic Report of the President, Washington DC: United
States Government Printing Office, 2005. Chapter 4, "Immigration."
http://www.gpoaccess.gov/eop/2005/2005_erp.pdf.
G. Hanson, "Illegal Migration from Mexico to the United States," Journal of Economic
Literature, 44 (2006): 869-924.
http://irpshome.ucsd.edu/faculty/gohanson/JEL_Mexican_Immigration_0306.pdf.
R. Lee and T. Miller, "Immigration, Social Security, and Broader Fiscal Impacts," American
Economic Review 90 (May 2000): 350-354.
http://www.jstor.org/view/00028282/ap000009/00a00700/0.
G. Ottaviano and G. Peri, "Rethinking the Effects of Immigration on Wages," NBER Working
Paper 12497 (2006). http://papers.nber.org/papers/w12497.
J. Passel, "The Size and Characteristics of the Unauthorized Migrant Population in the U.S.,"
Pew Hispanic Center, 2006. http://pewhispanic.org/files/reports/61.pdf.
J. Smith and B. Edmonston (eds.), The New Americans: Economic, Demographic, and Fiscal
Effects of Immigration, Washington DC: National Research Council, National Academy Press,
1997.
Table 1. —Median Weekly Earnings by Educational Attainment, 2006
Educational Attainment |
Native- born earnings |
Foreign- born earnings |
Foreign earnings as % of native earnings |
Foreign-born unemployment rate |
All |
$743 |
$575 |
77 |
3.6 |
Less than a high school diploma |
462 |
396 |
86 |
5.1 |
High school graduates, no college |
607 |
507 |
84 |
3.5 |
Some college, no degree |
701 |
613 |
87 |
3.4 |
College graduates |
1042 |
1024 |
98 |
2.3 |
Note: Wage data relate to full-time wage and salary workers aged 25 years and older. Unemployment data relate to those in the labor force aged 25 years and over.
Source: Department of Labor (Bureau of Labor Statistics).
|